Al
Shafi‘i reports that when Tawoos was in charge of administering alms from the
caravan on behalf of Mohammed bin Yousuf he came to the people and said: “Pay
your zakat (statutory charity), may Allah have mercy on you,
out of [the bounty] that Allah has given you.” When they did not pay it to him, he asked them: “Where are your poor?” Then, according
to al Shafi‘i, “he took [the payment] from this person and paid it to that
person without taking anything for himself; he did not profit by it and he did
not pay anything out of it to the Wali.” He added that when a member of the
caravan turned his back on him he did not say to him: ‘Come on. Hand it over.’
Al
Shafi‘i commented: “In my view this is acceptable . . . though I would prefer
him to have been suspicious of the ahl al suhman (‘people of the
shares’); he could then have inquired and made those accused [of concealing
their wealth] swear on oath [that they were telling the truth], because many of
them were cheating. No-one should harbour suspicions, make someone swear an
oath or assume charge until he has ‘put it in its place’. This does not apply
to anyone who has not ‘put it in its place’.”1
The
above paragraphs illustrate the problematic relationship between fiqh
(jurisprudence) and politics - that is to say, between the ‘ilmiy (“religious-scholarly”)
authorities and political rulers - and the impact of that relationship upon
Islamic fiqh, particularly the area of fiqh related to zakat.
Many students of the subject are under the false impression that fiqh is
based solely on an understanding of the scriptural text and believe that realities
on the ground have no part to play in the matter. In fact, both are relevant.
As al
Shafi‘i reported, Tawoos did not say “Come on. Hand it over” to a person who
turned his back on him. This indicates clearly that he was unwilling to impose
demands upon people in a state whose political legitimacy and religious
credentials he did not recognize. As we have seen in the above paragraphs, this
was an attitude al Shafi‘i approved of, though he noted that he would have
preferred to distinguish between two types of cases. In the first of these the zakat is to be “put
in its place” and the person in charge of administering the alms should “be
suspicious of the ahl al suhman (‘people of the shares’)” and inquire
into their affairs and make them swear an oath. In the second instance it is
not to be “put in its place”; in this case nobody should be regarded with
suspicion or made to swear an oath. Here al Shafi‘i’s approach seems to
demonstrate a more logical attitude towards dealing with the political
environment than was commonly the case.
Islamic
fiqh has developed as the result of an interaction between scriptural
text and realities on the ground; indeed, it could be described as the product
of a conflict between the religious scholars and the political rulers. After an
initial period of harmony which lasted throughout the time of the
Rightly-Guided Caliphs the religious and political establishments diverged,
creating a space between them that was occupied by a sort of “no-man’s-land” of
mutual suspicion in which the political ruler sought to the extent of resorting
to coercion - by making him swear an oath of allegiance, while the faqih
showed his refusal to do so by seeking refuge in
his scholarship and using his influence with the
general public to mobilise opposition to the ruler, or emir.
Conversely,
and unsurprisingly, when a faqih became closely affiliated to the
governing authority he also tended to use fiqh as a tool for
legitimizing the state’s rulers, while in its turn (and this was the faqih’s
ultimate aim) the political authority sought to use its power in order to
reinforce the din (religion) and the role of religion in the community.
However, when a separation occurred between the two, the faqih withdrew
from public life, studiously ignoring what was going on around him,
holding the political authority responsible for everything that was happening
in the wider world and devoting himself to “personal fiqh” - i.e. fiqh
of concern to the individual rather than the community or the Ummuh (Muslim
Nation). His focus would thus be on salvation in the next world and he would
ignore any worldly commitments. According to Dr. Taha Jabir al Alwani: “This
was a really major factor leading to the separation of fiqh and usul
alfiqh (the ‘roots’ of jurisprudence) from significant aspects of Muslim
‘practical’ life, with the result that [fiqh scholars] began to approach
many issues from a theoretical and idealistic angle. Consequently, their [fiqh]
became an expression of what Muslim life ought to be, rather than what it
actually was or could be.”2
When
there was a “glut” of zakat funds, those who controlled them began to
use them for their own purposes rather than those for which they were
originally designated. This led to a kind of tug-of-war between the emirs and
the fuqaha’ (pl. of faqih), in which the emirs used all the moral
and material means at their disposal to gain control of the funds so that they
could use them to strengthen the state (and also - on occasion - squander them
on luxuries). Meanwhile, the fuqaha’ used their “scholarly space” to try to
prevent those funds from being spent for purposes other than those for which
they were originally intended. During this period, which was critical for the
ruling regime’s legitimacy, the fuqaha’ sought to revive the model of
the Prophet (PBUH) and the Rightly-Guided Caliphs, and in this they were partly
successful.
From
the above we can conclude that the “space occupied by fiqh” was influenced
by the political environment. There are two models to consider here: firstly,
direct political intervention by the ruler “invading” the faqih’s space
and spreading ideas that serve political interests (this could involve fabricating
and propagating scriptural texts, winning the support of leading religious
figures in order to gain legitimacy for the regime among the masses, or
promoting fiqh opinions which serve the regime’s purposes), and secondly,
a situation in which the political and religious establishments vie with each
other in an attempt to dominate the public space.
If we
take a close look at the fiqh of zakat in particular, we may come
across some useful examples that could cast light on this subject. Although it
is a field which has not been sufficiently studied, a number of well-known Prophetic
Traditions are narrated in several books of Hadith. This one is particularly
familiar: “If an alms collector comes to you, let him leave you in a state of
contentment.”3Another Hadith states: “People of the A‘rab
(desert Arabs) came to the Messenger of Allah (PBUH)
and said: ‘Some alms collectors came to us and treated us unjustly.’
[The Prophet] replied: ‘Make your alms collectors contented.’ They said:
‘O Messenger of Allah, [what about] if they treat us unjustly?’ He replied:
‘Make your alms collectors contented.’” Another narration says: “[Make your
alms-collectors contented] even if you are treated
unjustly.”4
Since
Islam calls for justice and equity, we may wonder whether these narrations are
compatible with the values of justice promoted by the din, or whether they sanction injustice - which is
something no rational person can accept. It is not altogether unlikely that
these Hadith narrations were concocted to give theoretical support to the
abusive and despotic style of alms collection under the regimes of the Umayyad
and Abbasid states and provide religious justification for the benefit of the
political authority at that time. However, what is more probable is that they
were designed to underpin the Ash‘arite position, which sanctioned the notion
of kingship instead of a Caliphate while at the same time underlining the
principle of the sovereignty of the Shariah. (As Abdul Majid al Saghir points
out, this notion was not accepted by the majority of Muslims.)5
Anyone
who takes a close look at the texts of these narrations will also suspect their
authenticity due to the poor quality of the language.
Islam
gives the highest priority to the principle of justice, which it sees as the
basis of the relationship between ruler and subject, and the wealth an
individual is required to pay to the state falls into this category. The following
two Traditions give some indications of that relationship.
In the
first, two of the Prophet’s alms collectors came to the owner of some sheep and
said: “We have been sent by the Messenger of Allah (PBUH) to collect alms.” He
replied: “What alms?” They said: “A ewe from your [flock of] sheep.” He offered
them a young ewe with plenty of milk in its udders and they said: “We were not
instructed to [take] that.” Then he offered them one that was about to give
birth and they said: “We were not instructed to [take] that. We were not
instructed to [take] a pregnant animal or one full of milk.” So he offered them
a two-year-old or young she-goat. They accepted it; then they invoked blessings
upon him and went on their way.6
In the
second the Prophet sent a kharis (a man who collects the tithe on the date
harvest) [to collect the tithe] and a man came and complained about him to the
Prophet (PBUH) and said: “He made me pay more than my due.” So the Messenger
of Allah (PBUH) said [to the alms collector]: “Your cousin claims that you
made him pay more than his due.” He replied: “O Messenger of Allah, I
left him enough to [cover] his family’s nakedness, feed the poor and for what
the wind causes to fall.” So [the Prophet] said: “Your cousin did not
make you pay more than your due and he treated you fairly.”7
These
two Traditions show that the relationship between the individual and the state
was governed by the values of justice and fairness. The alms collector refused
to take more than he was instructed to, while if a person paying the alms felt
that he was being unjustly treated he had the right to lodge a complaint
against the alms collector. Moreover, his complaint would be listened to. This
continued to be the case throughout the time of the Rightly Guided Caliphs.
When
Abu Bakr al Siddiq sent Anas to Bahrain he gave him the following instruction:
“This is the obligatory alms payment decreed by the Messenger of Allah (PBUH)
for [all] Muslims, which Allah commanded His Messenger (PBUH) [to impose]. When
a Muslim is asked to pay the correct amount, he should pay it, while [anyone]
who is asked for more than that should not pay it.”8
This
instruction is in stark contrast to the narration we have quoted above which
contains the words “Even if you are treated unjustly”, which reflects the
desire of a grasping king to indulge his instincts for oppression and injustice
and provide him with easy access to wealth under the cloak of religion. Al
Nawawi was right to give Chapter 55 of his book Kitab al Zakat the title
“Bab Irdha’ al Sa‘iy Ma Lam Yatlub Haram” (“The Chapter on Giving
Gratification to the One Who Strives As Long As He ls Not Seeking
That Which is Forbidden”)9
However,
in the face of political oppression the faqih has no option but to submit to
the status quo and acquiesce in the power of the sword, since this is the only
way to protect the Ummuh (Islamic Nation/Community) from even worse
suffering and avert the danger of fitnah (turmoil/ subversion). I offer these two different views to
illustrate my point:
First, the view that it is permissible
to pay zakat to an unjust emir. Ibn Salam reports: “A man came to Ibn
‘Umar and said: ‘In your opinion, to whom should I pay zakat?’ He
replied: ‘Pay it to the emirs, even if they use it to [buy] meat for the dogs
at their tables.’” It is also reported that a man said to Ibn ‘Umar: “I have
funds, so to whom should I pay the zakat on them?” He replied: “Pay it
to these people.” (He meant the emirs.) [The man] said: “If [I do that,] they
will use it [to buy] clothes and perfume.” [Ibn ‘Umar] replied: “Even if they [spend] it on clothes and perfume [you
should pay it to them].”10
When
Sa‘id bin Jubair was asked about zakat, he gave this somewhat evasive
reply: “Pay it to the wali al ‘amr (person responsible).” In response the
questioner said: “You instruct me to pay it to the wali al ‘amr and he
will do this and that with it.” Sa‘id answered: “Put it where Allah commanded you
[to put it].” You ask me about people’s heads [- i.e. what is going on in their
minds -] and I am not in a position to inform you.”11
Second,
the view that it is permissible to pay tolls and taxes out of zukat
funds. Ibn Salam reports that Anas bin Malik and al Hasan said: “What has been paid on bridges and roads is sadaqah
madhiyah.” By this he meant that it was an acceptable alternative to zakat.
It is
reported that Ibrahim said: “Malik calculated zakat on what the tithe
collectors have taken from you.” Ibn Salam also narrated a number of
Traditions from the fatwas of the Tabi‘in (“Followers”
- i.e. the generation after the Prophet’s Companions) along with the
observation: “[The Traditions] we have are valid, although some of them may
give other opinions.”12
These two examples clearly show the
degree to which the faqih was prepared to make concessions to the ruling
authority. At the same time, they also represent a transitional period between
the original harmonious relationship between faqih and ruler and the
breakdown of that relationship, following which the faqih began to take
practical steps to protect his “fiqh space” and ensure that funds
designed for charitable purposes did not fall into the hands of the political
authority.
The evidence suggests that the first person
who tried to frame this concept in precise systematic terms was al Shafi‘i when
he devised usul al fiqh - a discipline in which he endeavoured to
establish the rules for ijtihad (interpretative judgement) and dealing
with scriptural texts. In doing so, as ‘Abdul Majid al Saghir13
points out, one of his aims was to protect the “fiqh space” and Islamic
Shariah concepts from being exploited by the ruling authority for its own ends.
Moving
on from usul al fiqh to furu‘ al fiqh (the “branches” – or specifics - of fiqh),
we find that al Shafi‘i sought to ensure that funds destined for charitable
purposes were removed from the control of the political authority. This
entailed four lines of approach:
First, he interpreted the Qur’anic verse on
charitable payments to mean that it was obligatory to distribute zakat
funds equally between the eight categories mentioned in that verse, and that it
was not permissible to spend them on any other category.14
Consequently, the wali al ‘amr had limited freedom in the way he
administered the funds. This was not actually a new fiqh position; it
had been current since the time of the Tabi‘in, though it had been
opposed by some fiqh scholars such as Abu ‘Ubaidah Muslim bin Abi Karimah
in his Risalah (Epistle) on Zakat.15 What al Shafi‘I did was
give prominence to the idea and establish it as the right and proper practice.
Second,
it was repeatedly stressed that zakat was the property of the poor by
right and that the state was not entitled to it. Apart from the Hadith “And
render it unto their poor,”16 there were no other scriptural texts
to provide clarification on how alms should be distributed, so consequently there
was a widely-held belief that the state should play no part in collecting alms
or in spending them on public affairs.
Third,
it was maintained that it was not permissible to transfer zakat to
another geographical to area until the needs of the people of the locality where
it had been collected had been satisfied. Once this was achieved, it should be transferred to the nearest or adjacent
locality. This principle ensured that it did not end up in the state capital.
Fourth,
zakat was completely separate from the state’s general funds.
All
these concepts were accepted by scholars from the different schools of fiqh.
Where there were disagreements, these were due either to contradictions
concerning some Hadith narrations, or differences in fiqh ideological
positions.
One
thing which will be apparent to any student of fiqh is the fact that the
fiqh governing zakat underwent significant changes in states
where the religious and political establishments were in harmony with each other.
One example of this is the case of ‘Uthman, who was not concerned with the
collection of zakat on amwal batinah (assets that are not visibly
identified, such as cash, gold, silver etc.) and was content to collect it only
on amwul dhahirah (visibly identifiable assets). The different schools of fiqh
had various interpretations over the way this should be understood. While their
positions were not identical, some of them (the Hanafis, Shafi‘is and Hanbalis)
wanted to emulate ‘Uthman and make his method a hard and fast rule that could
not be changed.
Their
approach simplified the matter considerably, eliminated the “interests aspect”
and gave the ijtihad opinion of one of the Prophet’s Companions the
status of an act of worship. Ultimately, though, it was based on a political
decision which gave religious endorsement to all those who maintained that zakat
on amwal batinah was not payable to the wali al ‘amr - either as
a matter of choice (in the case of the Hanafis) or as a “preferred” course of
action (in the case of the Shafi‘is and Hanbalis).
Opinions
on the question of the wali al ‘amr’s responsibility for collecting zakat
were strongly influenced by political factors, and the faqih’s attitude
to the state (whether “pro” or “anti”) was undoubtedly bound to affect his
view, because zakat collection is first and foremost an act that represents
the sovereign prerogative of the zakat collector. Therefore, it was natural that a “tame” faqih
should support the state on this question, though without ignoring the relevant
scriptural texts, while an “anti-state” faqih would oppose it insofar as
he was able to do so.
This
is how ‘Uthman’s position on not collecting zakat on amwal batinah
became an established law that no state could violate.
On
this question the Hanbali school - the school that had the most distant
relationship with the state - considered it preferable for a person to be
personally responsible for distinguishing between the two categories of his own
zakat payment himself. In its view this was better than paying it to a
just imam (possibly because of the trials and tribulations suffered by the school’s
founder - Ahmed bin Hanbal). The Shafi‘i position was similar and regarded
making a distinction between the categories of zakat payments as being
preferable, even if the person in charge of collecting them should demand
otherwise, and supports the view that al Shafi‘i basically devised usul al
din as a tool for protecting the fiqh “sector” from the power of the
politicians. Al Shafi‘i concluded that this was necessary after a long period during
which the community of fiqh scholars had suffered persecution by the ruling
authorities.
The
Hanafi position reflects Abu Hanifa’s cautious attitude to the ruling authority
after he himself had been persecuted by them. That is why he and Abu Yousuf
accepted ‘Uthman’s system as a Sunnah - a position that no-one has countermanded
since.17
The
lbadi and Maliki positions are consistent with those of the ruling authority
and approach the scriptural texts from the angle of “interests and Shariah
politics”. Where the Ibadis were concerned, this was due to a desire to
propagate their ideas and reinforce the power of their state, while the Malikis’ position reflected the close relationship that had
existed between Malik and the powers that be during his time, which was later
reproduced by the states that followed the Maliki school in the Arab Maghreb.
According to al Kindi’s Bayan al Shar‘(Explanation of the Law of
Islam): “If the imam is just, alms may only be delivered to him or his
employees,”18 while Malik states: “If the imam acts justly, there is
no scope for a man to differentiate between zakat on his cash assets and
[on his] other [assets].”19
Although
the ambiguity on zakat has its roots in the past, it is still very much
alive in present-day fiqh. In al Ashqar’s view the change in the prevailing
legal opinion on the subject dates from the end of the era of the
Rightly-Guided Caliphs, when fatwas were issued sanctioning concealment of zakat
on amwal batinah from the authorities and allowing it to be paid
directly to its recipients by the individual; this was because there was a
general feeling that the authorities were abusing their position over the
collection of zakat. It was concluded that the ideal solution was to follow
the “mabda’ al ijma‘iy” (“consensus principle”) that was eventually reached
by Muslim scholars after a long period of intensive debate.20
(It is interesting to note that the “mabda’ al
ijma‘iy” after ‘Uthman is still recognized. However, one is tempted to
wonder if there actually was a “mobda’ al ijma‘iy” or whether this is a
new expression which has a different meaning from the one we usually understand
by “ijma‘”, or “consensus”).
Other
scholars maintain that the whole subject is just another example of “Shariah
politics” and falls into the category of “the wali ul ‘amr’s prerogatives”.
Yousuf Hamid is convinced that that the ‘Uthman system gives the wali al
‘amr the specific right to authorise “arbab al amwal” (“owners of capital”) to pay out amwal batinah
as they see fit (from which we can understand that he also has the right to
authorise the disposal of amwal dhahirah in the same way), while it is
his responsibility (i.e. the responsibility of the wali al ‘amr himself)
to monitor the process. Moreover, if it is permissible to
authorise individuals to administer zakat, it follows that it must also
be permissible to grant collective authority to a body such as an institution,
establishment or association.21
Another
example of the convoluted relationship between fiqh and politics can be
seen in the legislation governing the relationship between the state and the
individual which, while one of its aims is to simplify procedures, can become a
tool for state oppression that has the effect of intimidating the faqih.
In
this connection, one issue which would seem self-evident and a matter of common
sense is the permissibility of zakat payment in cash rather than in
kind, though in the view of faqih scholars the rule is that payment in
kind is obligatory. However, I personally believe that this rule was originally
designed to protect people from any potential injustice on the part of the
state, which might otherwise force people to pay their alms in cash, gold or
silver when they would prefer to pay them in kind (in grain in the case of the
farmer, or livestock in the case of the stock-breeder etc.). After all, as far as the state is concerned it is
easier to deal in cash rather than in kind, because it is lighter to carry and
more flexible in the uses to which it can be put.
Malik
narrates an account of a man who forced people to pay their zakat in
dirhams and said: “I hope there will be recompense if they have paid the value
required of them appropriately.”22
There
are also a number of different fiqh opinions on the question of whether,
if a tyrant forces his subjects to pay zakat and they pay it to him, they have to pay it again to its lawful recipients.
On
this issue Abu Sa‘id al Kadmi says the predominant view is that there is “no
guarantee for subjects in that [matter],”23 while al ‘Awtabi maintains
that if a person liable to pay zakat pays it to an unjust person so that
he can distribute it and he distributes it to the poor in his presence, he will “receive recompense for it”24.
This means that the question of a person liable for zakat being forced
to pay something that is not in the “compulsory category” is a de facto
possibility which is recognized by fiqh scholars. Consequently, they
have sought to preclude that eventuality in order to minimise any potential
distress it might cause and safeguard the social fabric.
It is interesting to
note that over the centuries the faqih has always enjoyed pride of place
in the “scholarly hierarchy” - above his contemporaries in the fields of
letters, philosophy, theology and medicine. This intriguing fact deserves to be
studied as a separate subject in its own right.
_____________________________
* Scholar from the Sultanate
of Oman.
1 Al Umm, Dar al Fikr,
Beirut, 1422 AH (2002 CE), Part 2, p. 65.
2 Taha Jabir al ‘Alwani: Usul
al Fiqh al islami, International Institute of Islamic Thought, 2nd
impression, 1415 AH (1995 CE), p. 77.
3 Muslim No. 989.
4 Abu Dawud No. 1589.
5 See: AI Fikr al Usuli wa Ishkaliyyat
al Sultah al ‘llmiyyah fi’I Islam, Dar al Muntakhab al ‘Arabi, Al Mu’assasah al Jami ‘iyyah li’l Dirasat wa’l Nashr, Beirut, 1st
impression, 1415 AH (l994 CE), p. 22.
6 Abu Dawud No.1581.
7 Al Daraqutni: Kitub alZakat,
Bab al Kharas (27).
8 Abu Dawud, No. 1567.
9 Sahih Muslim Bisharh al
Nawawi: Dar Ihya’ alTurath al ‘Arabi, Beirut, 3rd impression,
vol. 4, part 7, p. 163.
10 Al Amwal, edited with
commentary by Mohammed Khalil Harras, Dar al Fikr, Beirut, 1408 AH (1988 CE),
p.681.
11 Ibid. p. 684.
12 Ibid. p. 629.
13 Al Fikr al Usuli wa Ishkaliyyat al Sultah al ‘ilmiyyah
fi’l Islam, p. 171.
14 Al Umm, vol. 2, p. 77.
15 Al Rashidi: Al Imam Abu ‘Ubaidah Muslim bin Abi
Karimah wa Fiqhuh, Matabi‘ al Wafa’, al Mansurah,1415 AH (1992 CE),
p. 515.
16 Al Bukhari, No. 1469.
17 See al Mawsili: Al
Ikhtiyar, with commentary by Khalid ‘Abdulrahman al ‘Akk, Dar al Ma‘rifah, Beirut, 2nd
impression, 1402 AH (2002 CE), part bl, p. 136.
18 Al Kindi. Revised by Abdul
Hafidh Shalabi, Ministry of National Heritage and Culture, Sultanate of Oman,
1402 AH (1982 CE), part 19, p. 253.
19 Al Mudawwanah al Kubra. Text verified by Mohammed
Mohammed Tamir, Maktabat al thaqafah al Diniyyah, Cairo, 1425AH (2004 CE),
paqrt 1, p. 344.
20 Al Ashqar: Al Ilzam bi’l Zakat fi’l Dhahir wa’l
Batin, part of a series of studies on present-day zakat issues, Dar al
Nafa’is. Jordan, 1st impression, 1418 AH.
21 Ilzamiyyat al Zakat wa
Tatbiqiha min Wali al ‘Amr, part of a series of papers presented at the
First Symposium on Contemporary Zakat Issues, p. 155.
22 Al Mudawwanah al Kubra,
part 1, p. 396.
23 Al Kindi: Bayan alShar‘, part
19, p.269.
24 Al Dhiya’, Ministry of National Heritage
and Culture, Sultanate of Oman, 1st impression, 1411 AH (1991 CE), part 6, p.
41.
Reference:
Fiqh (Islamic
Jurisprudence) and Its Heritage through the Eyes of the Faqih (Scholar of
Jurisprudence) and the Politician, by: Khalid bin Said al Mashrafi, Al-Tafahom
Magazine, issue number 11/2019.
No comments:
Post a Comment